A few days ago I began discussing the economic incidence of a tax. Closely related to this is the deadweight loss of a tax. On February 22 I wrote: "The deadweight loss comes from the reduction in economic activity caused by the tax. If the gain from a transaction between a buyer and a seller is $5, but the government imposes a $6 tax on the transaction, it will cause the transaction to disappear."
The main harm done by taxes is this deadweight loss. Taxes tend to reduce economic activity. Now the government programs funded by the tax might increase economic activity, or make citizens and residents better off in some way. If tax revenue is used to pay for a legal system, which by its existence reduces crimes by a sufficient amount, the gain from having the legal system will exceed the deadweight loss incurred by the taxes necessary to pay for the legal sytem. (By legal system I mean things like police, prosecutors, public defenders, prisons and courts.)
I presume that no one doubts that we need a legal system. However, it is conceivable that an increase in taxes imposed to pay for an expansion of the legal system (such as building a new courthouse or hiring more police) could cause a deadweight loss sufficiently large to be greater than the value to society of the expansion of the legal system. A new federal courthouse is to be built near where I live. Already the city has condemned property and thereby put many businesses out of business or forced them to move. The federal government is going to pay for the new courthouse, so local residents are not concerned about the deadweight loss of the taxes needed to pay for the new courthouse. Only a small part of those taxes will be raised locally. But the loss is there, and I don't think the new courthouse will make the area safer. But I digress.
Today's topic is the incidence of a tax. Suppose there is no tax on the production and sale of a good. If markets are perfectly competitive, then each buyer will spend dollars on the good until the value (to the buyer) of one additional unit of the good just equals its price. Each seller will be willing to supply additional units of the good to the market until the cost of providing one additional unit just equals the price of the good. If the price of bananas is 45 cents a pound, then I will buy pounds of bananas per month until the value to me of one more pound of bananas per month is just equal to 45 cents. I purchase more bananas than this, the value to me of each additional pound of bananas will be less than 45 cents.
Lets keep the price of bananas at 45 cents per pound and suppose the government imposes a tax of 10 cents per pound on bananas. And suppose the the government requires me, and other buyers, to pay this tax. In order for me to keep buying the same number of bananas per month the price would have to decline to 35 cents per pound. But if this happens, the seller of the last pound of bananas that I purchase will only get 35 cents for that pound, even though it costs him to 45 cents to provide me with that pound of bananas. Hence, the price cannot go down all the way to 35 cents per pound. What will tend to happen is that the price of bananas will decline a little bit, say to 40 cents per pound. Buyers, in this case, will pay 40 cents plus 10 cents in taxes--at total of 50 cents per pound--for each pound of bananas. Hence they buy fewer bananas. Sellers will supply fewer bananas to the market because they will not supply those bananas that cost it more than 40 cents per pound to supply. So the tax causes sellers to receive a smaller amount for each unit of their product, and buyers to pay a higher amount to purchase each unit of the product.
When there was no tax, the value to each buyer of the last pound of bananas purchased per month was 45 cents per pound. The cost to each seller of the last pound supplied was also 45 cents per pound. With the 10 cent tax per pound, the value to each buyer of the last pound of bananas purchased per month will exceed the cost to each supplier of supplying his last pound supplied by 10 cents. Each buyer will buy pounds of bananas until the value of the last pound per month is 50 cents, and suppliers will supply bananas until the cost of supplying the last pound is 40 cents. 50 minus 40 cents is 10 cents.
This gives us the information we need to calculate the incidence of the 10 cent tax on bananas. Before the tax was imposed, buyers paid 45 cents per pound for bananas, but now they pay 50 cents. So the incidence of buyers is 5 cents. The incidence of a tax on buyers is the increase in the amount that the buyer has to pay because of the tax. The incidence on sellers is also 5 cents in this example, because before the tax each seller received 45 cents per pound of bananas, but now they receive only 40 cents for each pound. The incidence of a tax on a seller is the decrease in price per unit of output received by the seller because of the tax.
The incidence of a tax is often expressed as a percentage. In this example buyers pay 50% of the tax and sellers pay 50% of the tax (because 5 cents is 50% of 10 cents). The tax is not always equally shared by buyers and sellers. What actually happens depends on how sensitive the demand for the taxed good is to price, as well as how sensitive the supply of the taxed good is to price. (We call these items the elasticity of demand and the elasticity of supply, respectively.) In general, the more sensitive to price the demand for the good is, the smaller the incidence on buyers. Likewise, the more sensitive supply is to price, the smaller the incidence is on sellers.
Interestingly enough, there are conditions under which the sensitivity of supply to price is so great that it is not possible for the price received by sellers to decline. This is a long-run or long-term possibility and the industries in which this can happen are called constant-cost industries. If an industry is a constant cost industry, then the incidence of any tax imposed upon it will fall entirely on buyers.
Suppose an industry is a constant cost industry. Suppose all the producers in this industry are really rich. The government decides to tax them because they are rich. Suppose the people who buy the good are either poor or are typically people with low incomes. The incidence of the tax then will fall entirely or almost entirely on people who are poor, even though by statute the "rich" are suppose to pay the tax. The economic incidence of a tax does not depend upon the statutory incidence of the tax. You can tax the rich and by doing so make the poor worse off.
There are also examples where it is the behavior of buyers that causes incidence to fall entirely or nearly entirely on sellers and in which the buyers are "rich" and the sellers are "poor". A good example of this is the luxury tax. Luxurious goods are not necessarily produced by the rich for rich, they can be produced by the poor for the rich. But by its very nature a luxury good or service is not a necessity. People do not have to have it. If it is taxed, the quantity of the good or service demanded declines greatly, causing the amount produced to decline and incomes of producers to decline because price declines. Consider a tax on employing domestic help. Since this is not a necessity, households that employ housekeepers, nannies, and cooks will tend to greatly reduce their employment of domestic employees, or conspire with them not to pay the tax. This is why so many nominees to cabinent positions have "nanny" tax problems.
Wednesday, March 4, 2009
Monday, March 2, 2009
Are the markets voting no confidence in the Obama administration?
Although my numbers are only approximations, the Obama administration appears to be getting very low marks from United States financial markets. During the two months from the November 2008 elections to the first week in January the Dow Jones Industrial Average declined about 5%. During the last 8 weeks, it has declined by 25%.
There is a theory that active traders in the stock market (or any other market that reflects expectations of the future) use all information at their exposure when making decisions about at what prices they are willing to buy and sell equities. This is a called the efficient market hypothesis. The idea is that market prices reflect all available information. Speculators use new information to change the prices at which they are willing to buy or sell any particular common stock (or bond or other financial instrument). Properly understood the efficient market hypothesis does not imply that prices always reflect all available information, rather it implies that prices move very quickly to reflect such information. The practical application of this to personal investing is that if I read the financial news every morning, reflect on it for a few hours, and then decide to buy or sell common stock based on what I have absorbed, unless I have some insight that noone else has, market prices will already reflect this news.
When looking at how the markets evaluate the Obama administration we can use the efficient market hypothesis because it implies that the decline in the stock market this morning (Monday, March 2) reflects new information, information that market participants did not have on Friday, February 27. Indeed, the entire decline in the stock market since President Obama's election implies that, taken as a whole, what President Obama has revealed about the kind of economic policy he intends to follow, has had a profound negative effect on the economy--and especially a profound negative effect on what equity market participants expect will happen to economic growth in the future.
The market is voting no confidence in the Obama administration!

There is a theory that active traders in the stock market (or any other market that reflects expectations of the future) use all information at their exposure when making decisions about at what prices they are willing to buy and sell equities. This is a called the efficient market hypothesis. The idea is that market prices reflect all available information. Speculators use new information to change the prices at which they are willing to buy or sell any particular common stock (or bond or other financial instrument). Properly understood the efficient market hypothesis does not imply that prices always reflect all available information, rather it implies that prices move very quickly to reflect such information. The practical application of this to personal investing is that if I read the financial news every morning, reflect on it for a few hours, and then decide to buy or sell common stock based on what I have absorbed, unless I have some insight that noone else has, market prices will already reflect this news.
When looking at how the markets evaluate the Obama administration we can use the efficient market hypothesis because it implies that the decline in the stock market this morning (Monday, March 2) reflects new information, information that market participants did not have on Friday, February 27. Indeed, the entire decline in the stock market since President Obama's election implies that, taken as a whole, what President Obama has revealed about the kind of economic policy he intends to follow, has had a profound negative effect on the economy--and especially a profound negative effect on what equity market participants expect will happen to economic growth in the future.
The market is voting no confidence in the Obama administration!
Sunday, March 1, 2009
When the government increases its spending, can it increase total spending?
This is a serious question and just about everyone these days is assuming the answer is yes. I recently read a nice paper by John Taylor that argues that the use of countercyclical fiscal policy (other than automatic stabilizers) is not really desirable. But this is different from asserting that an increase in government spending per se does not increase total spending. I don't know whether Professor Taylor agrees with the argument I present below, but it has been a very long time since I have discussed this issue with anyone. The reason that I have not discussed it much with anyone is because, as Taylor points out in his paper, for at least the last 15 years there has been widespread agreement that activist countercyclical fiscal policy is usually not effective in stabilizing the economy. Be that as it may, I don't think that increasing government spending per se can increase total spending. Here is why.
In order to increase its spending, the government must either borrow the money, or print new money. If the government increases its spending by printing money, then its policy is no longer an increase in government spending per se, because the printing of additional money is an act of monetary policy. Hence the only way it can increase its spending as a pure act of fiscal policy is to borrow the money. But if the government borrows the money, then those that lend to government cannot spend the money themselves, nor can they lend it to someone else, who would spend it. First consider someone with $10,000 who plans to spend it himself. The government comes along and decides to borrow another
400 or 500 billion dollars. Is this going to prevent this person from spending his $10,000? If the answer is no not only for this person, but also for the 40 million other people from whom the government would have to borrow $10,000, then the government would not be able to increase its spending unless it does something to persuade these people to change their mind. The only way the government can do this is to being willing to borrow at an interest rate higher than that that currently prevails in the market place. That is, the government can only borrow the 400 to 500 billion dollars in this case by pushing up interest rates enough to persuade spenders to save rather than spend.
But some potential lenders to the governemt, rather than spend the money themselves, would have loaned their money to someone else rather than Uncle Sam. They would have loaned their $10,000 to someone else if Uncle Sam does not come along and borrow it. But the someone else who would have borrowed money surely would have spent the borrowed money. Why else does someone borrow money excpet to spend it? (Possibly to buy a new car, do home repairs, or to invest in a business--but spend it nonetheless.) But if that someone else did intend to spend the money, the government, by borrowing the money itself, prevents that someone else from spending the $10,000. That is, the government's decision to borrow 400 to 500 billion dollars prevents the private sector from spending that money itself. Hence the government cannot increase total spending by an increase in its own spending if those it borrows from (1) would have otherwise spent the money themselves, or (2) would have otherwise loaned the money to someone else.
There is one final possibility, however. This is the possibility that those who would lend the money to Uncle Sam otherwise would have simply held on to the 400 to 500 billion dollars, letting it sit in their bank account or leaving it hidden in mattresses. Is it possible that there is enough money sitting around for this to happen? At the time I am writing this the stock of United States currency held by the public is about $830 billion. (I think that about 40% of this is actually held overseas.) The amount of money held in the form of bank deposits is about $720 billion. So the narrowly defined stock of money is currently a little less than $1,600 billion, with perhaps only about $1,200 held within the United States. This implies that the economy needs about $1,200 billion worth of money narrowly defined to make its normal transactions. If people could make their normal transactions with only $800 billion, then it might be possible to persuade them to lend some of it to the government. But why would Americans hold the money they hold unless they need it to make their normal transactions? Any money not needed for normal transactions can be deposited in bank accounts that pay more interest than currency (which pays none) or the type of checkable deposits that are included in the narrowly defined money stock. Hence, if there is enough money sitting around in bank accounts that people could use to lend to Uncle Sam, it must be in accounts which depository institutions are already using to lend to other borrowers. That is, it is unlikely that there are "idle" holdings of money that the general public would or could use to lend to the government to finance an increase in government spending.
There are macroeconomic models in which increases in government spending cause an increase in total spending. Within the IS-LM model, the model developed by John Hicks, what happens is actually consistent with the above. Within the IS-LM model an increase in government spending financed by borrowing does increase total spending but only because the resulting increases in the rate of interest cause households and business to wish to hold less money--that is, part of the lending to the government comes from the decision of households to hold less money relative to their income. If increases in the rate of interest do not cause people to wish to hold less money, then the increase in government spending will not cause an increase in total spending within the IS-LM model because the LM curve will be vertical.
As a result, it must be concluded that the recently passed stimulus package will not help the United States economy recover from the current recession.

In order to increase its spending, the government must either borrow the money, or print new money. If the government increases its spending by printing money, then its policy is no longer an increase in government spending per se, because the printing of additional money is an act of monetary policy. Hence the only way it can increase its spending as a pure act of fiscal policy is to borrow the money. But if the government borrows the money, then those that lend to government cannot spend the money themselves, nor can they lend it to someone else, who would spend it. First consider someone with $10,000 who plans to spend it himself. The government comes along and decides to borrow another
400 or 500 billion dollars. Is this going to prevent this person from spending his $10,000? If the answer is no not only for this person, but also for the 40 million other people from whom the government would have to borrow $10,000, then the government would not be able to increase its spending unless it does something to persuade these people to change their mind. The only way the government can do this is to being willing to borrow at an interest rate higher than that that currently prevails in the market place. That is, the government can only borrow the 400 to 500 billion dollars in this case by pushing up interest rates enough to persuade spenders to save rather than spend.
But some potential lenders to the governemt, rather than spend the money themselves, would have loaned their money to someone else rather than Uncle Sam. They would have loaned their $10,000 to someone else if Uncle Sam does not come along and borrow it. But the someone else who would have borrowed money surely would have spent the borrowed money. Why else does someone borrow money excpet to spend it? (Possibly to buy a new car, do home repairs, or to invest in a business--but spend it nonetheless.) But if that someone else did intend to spend the money, the government, by borrowing the money itself, prevents that someone else from spending the $10,000. That is, the government's decision to borrow 400 to 500 billion dollars prevents the private sector from spending that money itself. Hence the government cannot increase total spending by an increase in its own spending if those it borrows from (1) would have otherwise spent the money themselves, or (2) would have otherwise loaned the money to someone else.
There is one final possibility, however. This is the possibility that those who would lend the money to Uncle Sam otherwise would have simply held on to the 400 to 500 billion dollars, letting it sit in their bank account or leaving it hidden in mattresses. Is it possible that there is enough money sitting around for this to happen? At the time I am writing this the stock of United States currency held by the public is about $830 billion. (I think that about 40% of this is actually held overseas.) The amount of money held in the form of bank deposits is about $720 billion. So the narrowly defined stock of money is currently a little less than $1,600 billion, with perhaps only about $1,200 held within the United States. This implies that the economy needs about $1,200 billion worth of money narrowly defined to make its normal transactions. If people could make their normal transactions with only $800 billion, then it might be possible to persuade them to lend some of it to the government. But why would Americans hold the money they hold unless they need it to make their normal transactions? Any money not needed for normal transactions can be deposited in bank accounts that pay more interest than currency (which pays none) or the type of checkable deposits that are included in the narrowly defined money stock. Hence, if there is enough money sitting around in bank accounts that people could use to lend to Uncle Sam, it must be in accounts which depository institutions are already using to lend to other borrowers. That is, it is unlikely that there are "idle" holdings of money that the general public would or could use to lend to the government to finance an increase in government spending.
There are macroeconomic models in which increases in government spending cause an increase in total spending. Within the IS-LM model, the model developed by John Hicks, what happens is actually consistent with the above. Within the IS-LM model an increase in government spending financed by borrowing does increase total spending but only because the resulting increases in the rate of interest cause households and business to wish to hold less money--that is, part of the lending to the government comes from the decision of households to hold less money relative to their income. If increases in the rate of interest do not cause people to wish to hold less money, then the increase in government spending will not cause an increase in total spending within the IS-LM model because the LM curve will be vertical.
As a result, it must be concluded that the recently passed stimulus package will not help the United States economy recover from the current recession.
25th Wedding Anniversary
It snowed today. I took some pictures, and when looking at them I found this picture taken at a party given for us to celebrate our silver wedding anniverary. It was also in celebration of my father-in-law's 75th birthday, my daughter and niece graduating from college and my wife's uncle and aunt's 50th wedding anniversary. The party was in September 2008, the day University of Alabama played Tulane. The anniversary date was July 30, 2008.
Sunday, February 22, 2009
The Economic Incidence of a Tax--part one
There is no doubt that the recently passed economic stimulus package will not stimulate the United States economy. The Obama administration is now going to turn its attention to the budget deficit. But why? If the stimulus package is good for the economy, balancing the budget must be bad. There are no economic models that specify otherwise.
Since the 1960's research on the effect of fiscal policy (government spending and taxing policy) has shown that tax cuts and increases in government spending do not stimulate the demand side of the economy. Tax cuts, however, do reduce the deadweight loss to society from taxes. Tax increases, which is what the Obama administration is going to propose to reduce the government's budget deficit, will increase the deadweight loss to society from taxes.
A deadweight loss is a loss to one group in society that is not offset by a gain elsewhere. Taxes collected are not a loss to society as a whole because they might be used to allow the government to provide a valuable good are service (such as national defense, the legal system, and possibly highways, etc.). The deadweight loss comes from the reduction in economic activity caused by the tax. If the gain from a transaction between a buyer and a seller is $5, but the government imposes a $6 tax on the transaction, it will cause the transaction to disappear.
Suppose I could work an extra hour and earn $75. My gain from working an extra hour is not $75, rather it is $75 minus the opportunity cost of my time. Suppose the cost of my time is $50. That is, if the pay for my extra hour's work is less than $50, I will not work the extra hour. If the government taxes me at a rate of 34%, and I am paid only $75 for working one more hour, then I only have $49.50 after taxes, an amount less than my $50 opportunity cost of working an extra hour.
Hence, I do not work the extra hour.
It is odd to me that many people do realize how high are marginal taxes (the taxes from working an additional hour or earning an additional dollar) in the United States. A self-employed person pays 15.3% of his earning in social security and medicare taxes (although part of this is deductible), while both employer and employee pay 7.65% of each dollar earned, for a total tax rate of 15.3%, up to earnings of $106,800. In 2009 a couple that is married, filing jointly with a taxable income of $70,000 will pay a tax of 25% on each additional dollar earned. If both husband and wife are working, they will also both have incomes below the $106,800 ceiling on social security taxes. Hence for each additional dollar they earn, they pay about 40% in federal taxes. If there is a state income tax, the tax rate for a taxable income of $70,000 is above 4% in nearly all states that have an income tax. This makes their marginal tax rate 44%. Finally, where I live state and local sales taxes total 9%. Hence for each dollar earned and spent, about 53% goes to local, state and federal governments. (The state income tax rate is actually 5% where I live, so the total tax rate is 54%.) A husband and wife who jointly have a taxable income of $70,000 are not poor, but they certainly are not rich. But if they decide to work hard to earn extra money, they will find that various governments in our dear country get a larger share of their additional earnings than they do.
Gee, is this fair?
I don't think it is, but the Obama administration does. They argue that they can increase tax rates on those earning much higher incomes, say those who earn more than $250,000 per year. But there are not that many people who earn that much. Besides, if the tax rate on an additional dollar earned becomes as high as 60 or 70%, people who are capable of earning incomes over $250,000 will figure out ways to earn their incomes in a manner that is not taxable or they might even decide not to earn it at all.
It will be interesting to see whether the current administration can tax the private sector heavily without destroying it. Finally, it will interesting to see if the administration can figure out the fact that the economic incidence of a tax is different from the statutory incidence. If my income is taxed at a rate of 55%, then I pay 55 cents in taxes for each additional dollar that I earn. But because the high tax rate causes me to reduce the number of hours that I work, I don't produce as much output as otherwise. The reduction in my output can make someone else worse off. If I were a physician and decided to take longer vacations because of my high marginal tax rate, and/or charge more for my services, it would make my patients worse off. They might be poor.
My next post will discuss this further.
Since the 1960's research on the effect of fiscal policy (government spending and taxing policy) has shown that tax cuts and increases in government spending do not stimulate the demand side of the economy. Tax cuts, however, do reduce the deadweight loss to society from taxes. Tax increases, which is what the Obama administration is going to propose to reduce the government's budget deficit, will increase the deadweight loss to society from taxes.
A deadweight loss is a loss to one group in society that is not offset by a gain elsewhere. Taxes collected are not a loss to society as a whole because they might be used to allow the government to provide a valuable good are service (such as national defense, the legal system, and possibly highways, etc.). The deadweight loss comes from the reduction in economic activity caused by the tax. If the gain from a transaction between a buyer and a seller is $5, but the government imposes a $6 tax on the transaction, it will cause the transaction to disappear.
Suppose I could work an extra hour and earn $75. My gain from working an extra hour is not $75, rather it is $75 minus the opportunity cost of my time. Suppose the cost of my time is $50. That is, if the pay for my extra hour's work is less than $50, I will not work the extra hour. If the government taxes me at a rate of 34%, and I am paid only $75 for working one more hour, then I only have $49.50 after taxes, an amount less than my $50 opportunity cost of working an extra hour.
Hence, I do not work the extra hour.
It is odd to me that many people do realize how high are marginal taxes (the taxes from working an additional hour or earning an additional dollar) in the United States. A self-employed person pays 15.3% of his earning in social security and medicare taxes (although part of this is deductible), while both employer and employee pay 7.65% of each dollar earned, for a total tax rate of 15.3%, up to earnings of $106,800. In 2009 a couple that is married, filing jointly with a taxable income of $70,000 will pay a tax of 25% on each additional dollar earned. If both husband and wife are working, they will also both have incomes below the $106,800 ceiling on social security taxes. Hence for each additional dollar they earn, they pay about 40% in federal taxes. If there is a state income tax, the tax rate for a taxable income of $70,000 is above 4% in nearly all states that have an income tax. This makes their marginal tax rate 44%. Finally, where I live state and local sales taxes total 9%. Hence for each dollar earned and spent, about 53% goes to local, state and federal governments. (The state income tax rate is actually 5% where I live, so the total tax rate is 54%.) A husband and wife who jointly have a taxable income of $70,000 are not poor, but they certainly are not rich. But if they decide to work hard to earn extra money, they will find that various governments in our dear country get a larger share of their additional earnings than they do.
Gee, is this fair?
I don't think it is, but the Obama administration does. They argue that they can increase tax rates on those earning much higher incomes, say those who earn more than $250,000 per year. But there are not that many people who earn that much. Besides, if the tax rate on an additional dollar earned becomes as high as 60 or 70%, people who are capable of earning incomes over $250,000 will figure out ways to earn their incomes in a manner that is not taxable or they might even decide not to earn it at all.
It will be interesting to see whether the current administration can tax the private sector heavily without destroying it. Finally, it will interesting to see if the administration can figure out the fact that the economic incidence of a tax is different from the statutory incidence. If my income is taxed at a rate of 55%, then I pay 55 cents in taxes for each additional dollar that I earn. But because the high tax rate causes me to reduce the number of hours that I work, I don't produce as much output as otherwise. The reduction in my output can make someone else worse off. If I were a physician and decided to take longer vacations because of my high marginal tax rate, and/or charge more for my services, it would make my patients worse off. They might be poor.
My next post will discuss this further.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)